S. Marien, The effect of electoral outcomes on political trust A multi–level analysis of 23 countries, Electoral Studies 2011, Vol 30, Iss 4.pdf

(398 KB) Pobierz
Electoral Studies 30 (2011) 712
726
Contents lists available at ScienceDirect
Electoral Studies
The effect of electoral outcomes on political trust: A multi
level analysis
of 23 countries
So
e Marien
Centre for Political Research, University of Leuven, Parkstraat 45, Box 3602, 3000 Leuven, Belgium
article info
abstract
Article history:
Received 28 June 2010
Received in revised form 5 April 2011
Accepted 27 June 2011
Competing theoretical claims exist in the literature on the effect of proportionality on
political trust. To date, empirical studies yielded mixed results. In this paper, we examine
a curvilinear effect of the proportionality of election outcomes on political trust using data
from the European Social Survey (2006
ndings show that political trust is
indeed highest in countries with very proportional as well as in countries with very
disproportional election outcomes and lowest in countries that fall in between. Election
outcomes that are more fully inclusive and those that provide more accountability can
both lead to higher levels of political trust. Next to the proportionality of the translation of
votes into seats, this study investigates a broad range of election outcomes that are
associated with (dis)proportionality i.e. the effect of the number of parties in elections,
parliament and government, voting for the winning or losing party under different levels
of proportionality and the clarity of responsibility.
2009). The
Keywords:
Political trust
Election outcomes
Comparative
European Social Survey
2011 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction
politicians and hold them accountable ( Sartori, 1994 ).
Political trust is believed to be affected by electoral
outcomes such as the proportionality of the election
outcome, the number of political parties participating in
elections, in parliament and in of
In the last decades, there has been a renewal of interest
in the effect of electoral outcomes on political trust.
Widespread dissatisfaction with politics has been inter-
preted as the result of dissatisfaction with the functioning
of the electoral system. Electoral reform is often seen as
a way to restore political trust with recent examples of
electoral reforms that aimed to do this in New Zealand,
Italy and Japan ( Dalton, 2004 :177
ce. Also whether the
political party one voted for gains of
ce is argued to
in
uence political trust, especially when the election
outcome is disproportional the
gains substantial
representation and power in relation to the
winner
.In
addition, clarity of responsibility is also theorized to raise
political trust levels. While scholars agree upon the
importance of these election outcomes on political trust,
the direction of the effects is still debated. For one,
proportional as well as disproportional election outcomes,
single-party governments as well as coalitions are believed
to increase political trust levels. Moreover, despite the
substantial literature on the effects of electoral outcomes
on the attitudes of citizens toward the political system,
empirical studies testing these propositions have been in
much shorter supply and evidence emerging from the
existing studies is far from conclusive. For example,
loser
187; Shugart and
Wattenberg, 2001 ). Also the emergence of new democra-
cies and cases of divided societies has stimulated research
interest in the effect of electoral design and its outcomes on
political trust ( Lijphart, 1999; Farrell and McAllister, 2006 ).
The electoral system links citizens and elites and political
trust is considered to be an indication of the quality of this
linkage ( Aarts and Thomassen, 2008 ). In effect, through
elections citizens can communicate their preferences to
E-mail address: So
e.marien@soc.kuleuven.be .
0261-3794/$
see front matter
2011 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
887560969.015.png 887560969.016.png 887560969.017.png 887560969.018.png 887560969.001.png 887560969.002.png 887560969.003.png 887560969.004.png 887560969.005.png
S. Marien / Electoral Studies 30 (2011) 712
726
713
proportional as well as disproportional election outcomes
are found to foster political trust or no relation is found at
all ( Lijphart, 1999; Norris, 2011 :217
direct result of satisfaction with particular outputs of the
system. However, con
icting demands exist and not all
235; Wagner et al.,
demands can be satis
outputs cannot help
but provide a weak reed upon which a system might rest
its full weight
ed thereby
2009 ). Farrell and McAllister
(2006 : 724) conclude:
Whether and how electoral systems can affect levels of
satisfaction with democracy is therefore unresolved; work
is required.
( Easton, 1965 : 277). Therefore, Easton
(1965 : 273) highlights the importance of a second type
of support
In this article two theoretical approaches are
combined, proposing a curvilinear effect of proportion-
ality on political trust: political trust is highest in coun-
tries with very proportional and very disproportional
election outcomes and it is lowest in countries that fall in
between. This theoretical expectation provides a pro-
mising way to investigate the effect of proportionality on
political trust given the competing theoretical claims and
the mixed empirical evidence in the literature. Next to the
proportionality of the election outcome, the effect on
political trust of a large number of election outcomes is
investigated. This study adds to the literature by
proposing this curvilinear effect of proportionality on
political trust as well as by providing an overview of the
relation between a broad range of election outcomes and
political trust. First, the importance of political trust is
discussed. Subsequently, we provide an overview of the
theoretical arguments and previous empirical research on
the relationship between electoral outcomes and political
trust. Next, we turn to comparative survey data to analyze
the
a reservoir
of favorable attitudes or good will that helps members to
accept or tolerate outputs to which they are opposed or
the effect of which they see as damaging to their wants.
diffuse support
which serves as
Political trust is de
ned as an expression of diffuse rather
than speci
cally to the
regime and the political authorities ( Easton, 1975 ). In-line
with David Easton, political trust is considered in this
study as an expression of diffuse support which is not the
mere result of satisfaction of individual demands. The
focus of this study is trust in the regime and trust in
political institutions in particular. Political institutions play
an important role in shaping a democratic society, we can
assume that trust in these institutions is strongly related
to a more general evaluation of the political system.
Theoretically, we can assume that a critical attitude
toward the current leaders can be seen as healthy for
democracy. Nevertheless, citizens should be able to put
trust in the democratic procedures and institutions as
such, i.e. the system level. Politicians can be easily
replaced through elections but strong distrust in the
fundamental institutions of a democracy is less easily
restored ( Dalton, 2004 :157
c support and it is attributed speci
relationship
between
election
outcomes
and
political trust. The main
ndings are summarized in the
159; Klingemann and Fuchs,
conclusion.
1995 :2
5; Anderson et al., 2005 ).
2. The importance of political trust
3. Election outcomes and political trust
Political trust is at the center of democratic theory.
It
Scholars have argued that political trust is promoted
through the inherent fairness and inclusiveness of
proportional election outcomes ( Lijphart, 1999 ).
Conversely, political trust is also believed to be fostered by
disproportional outcomes as these promote accountability
and effectiveness ( Aarts and Thomassen, 2008 ). These
different characteristics result from the distinct goals that
underlie different electoral systems:
re
ects evaluations of whether or not political authorities
and institutions are performing in accordance with the
normative expectations held by the public
( Miller and
Listhaug, 1990 : 358). Political trust operates as
a heuristic devise that guides all kinds of behavior such as
participation in politics, law abidance or the willingness to
contribute to the collective good ( Hetherington, 1999;
Scholz and Lubell, 1998 ). Citizens with higher political
trust levels are more likely than distrusting citizens to
accept and comply with political decisions voluntarily,
thereby political trust enables political authorities to
collect resources and implement political decisions more
effectively ( Tyler, 1990; Marien and Hooghe, 2011 ). As
a result, political trust is a key resource for a political
system to authoritatively allocate values for society
( Easton, 1965 ). However, some authors have argued that
critical citizens can force political systems and political
decision makers to react in a more responsive manner to
demands from the population ( Norris, 1999; Rosanvallon,
2008; Gei
the major difference
between the majoritarian and proportional vision is their
view on the essence of democratic government and
consequently the function of elections
( Aarts and
Thomassen, 2008 : 6). Proportional election outcomes
are generally seen as more fair than the disproportional
outcome ( Sartori, 1994 ). Seats
were allocated to parties in proportion to the votes they
received at election, as a result voters determine to a great
extent which parties obtain seats and only few votes are
wasted ( Karp and Banducci, 2008 ). A proportional elec-
tion outcome is generally characterized by inclusiveness.
In effect, proportional electoral rules aim to lower the
threshold for parliamentary representation encouraging
more parties to enter the electoral contest resulting in the
presentation of various alternatives to the electorate, from
extreme-right parties to extreme-left parties to pirate-
parties or animal parties etc. As party choice can effec-
tively be used to voice (speci
the winner takes it all
b
el, 2008 ). By critically examining govern-
ment
s policy and governance, citizens keep government
of
cials accountable on a permanent basis. Nevertheless,
most authors agree that some level of political trust is
needed for the stability and functioning of democratic
societies.
David Easton has made an important distinction
between diffuse and speci
c) political preferences,
citizens
uence is strengthened. New issues
cherished by the public can more easily be put on the
feeling of in
c support. The latter is the
714
S. Marien / Electoral Studies 30 (2011) 712
726
agenda by new minor parties and discontent can be
voiced by voting on minor protest parties which can
channel this discontent into the parliamentary arena
( Miller and Listhaug, 1990 ). A proportional election
outcome signi
proportional outcomes are associated with inclusiveness
and representativeness, disproportional outcomes are
associated with government accountability and effective-
ness. Proportional outcomes mean a proportional trans-
lation of votes into seats and are generally associated with
a large number of political parties in elections, parliament
and government. Disproportional outcomes, on the other
hand, mean a disproportional translation of votes into
seats and are in general associated with fewer political
parties in elections, parliament and generally single-party
governments.
es more inclusive representation of the
whole electorate and its opinions given that more political
parties are also passing the threshold to parliamentary
representation. As a result, also political minorities are
represented in parliament and can in
uence political
decision-making ( Lijphart, 1994; Karp and Banducci,
2008 ). Finally, this inclusiveness also relates to the
number of parties in of
ce. Coalitions have the advantage
that a broad range of interests nd their way to policy and
this policy is found to be closer to the median voter than
the policy of single-party governments ( McDonald and
Budge, 2005 ).
By contrast, disproportional rules are intended to
fabricate clear majorities often associated with two-party
systems ( Sartori, 1994 ). In effect, disproportional rules
4. Previous empirical research
Following electoral reform toward more proportionality
in New Zealand citizens felt signi
cantly more political
ef
cacious and government was perceived as more
responsive ( Banducci et al., 1999 ). However, it is possible
that these changes are the result of enthusiasm for the
reform and not the increased proportionality as such. Given
that only few countries changed their electoral system so
profoundly in recent years ( Farrell, 2001 ), most research on
the relationship between the proportionality of electoral
outcomes and political trust is based on cross-national
comparisons. These studies yield contradicting results
showing higher levels of political trust in proportional
systems ( Lijphart, 1999 :275
do
not seek a parliament that re
ects the voting distribution;
they seek a clear winner. Their intent is not only to elect
a parliament but at the same time elect (if only by impli-
cation) a government
( Sartori, 1994 : 5). In general two
(blocks of) parties are competing in elections, the winner of
the election takes over the government and can implement
a clear policy (change). The party in government does not
have to compromise so much as a coalition government
does. When a single party is in of
287) and in disproportional
ce, the policy responsi-
bility is clear whereas responsibility is more diffuse in
coalition governments:
systems ( Norris, 1999 :217
nding no relationship
at all ( Listhaug et al., 2009; Norris, 2011; Wagner et al.,
2009 ). Further, empirical studies found higher trust levels
in countries with more parties contesting elections ( Weil,
1989 : 699). Miller and Listhaug (1990) concluded that the
varying thresholds for parliamentary representation were
crucial in determining the target, level and trends in
political distrust. In Norway which had a rather low
threshold for parliamentary representation, new parties
won seats in elections and disaffected voters were repre-
sented, whereas in US and Sweden discontent was accu-
mulated and resulted in higher levels of distrust:
235) or
usually there is an overlap
between the new and the old coalition, blurring the clarity
of responsibility and making the sanction of elections as an
instrument of accountability into a rather blunt weapon
( Aarts and Thomassen, 2008 : 7; See also Powell, 1989 ). The
rotation of parties in power is emphasized rather than
inclusiveness. In effect, inclusiveness can signify that
a party losing the election returns to power making it
dif
235;
Powell, 1989 ). As a result voters might incline to think that
it does not matter who is in power leading to resignation
and alienation. Next to this clarity of responsibility, single-
party governments are seen as more effective governments.
In the debate on electoral reform in New Zealand one of the
main concerns when implementing more proportional
electoral rules (and accordingly more proportional
outcomes) was a decrease in accountability and the effec-
tiveness of government ( Vowles et al., 2006 :268
cult to
vote the rascals out
( Norris, 2011 :217
the
institution of elections has failed, during the past twenty
years, to act as a mechanism for reducing the accumulating
dissatisfaction in either Sweden or the United States
( Miller and Listhaug, 1990 : 383). However, some evidence
suggests that party fragmentation lowers political trust
( Norris, 2011 :217
235; Weil, 1989 ). But in other studies
fractionalization indices failed to reach statistical signi
-
270).
Coalitions, especially with many parties, are argued to be
more unstable and more often lead to policy impasse ( Weil,
1989 ).
Finally, citizens voting for the party that won the
election gain more in an electoral system producing
disproportional outcomes, therefore, they are thought to
have higher levels of political trust than winners in
a system that produces more proportional outcomes.
Voters of parties that have lost the election, on the other
hand, are theorized to be better off with proportional
election outcomes than disproportional ones ( Anderson
et al., 2005 ).
In sum, both proportional and disproportional election
outcomes are theorized to foster political trust. While
cance ( Wagner et al., 2009; Van der Meer, 2010 ).
Further, political trust was found to be higher in coun-
tries with coalition governments, but too much coalition
partners diminished political trust levels again ( Anderson
et al., 2005 ). It is argued that in such countries elites
rather than election outcomes determine the composition
of government. Cabinet instability is also found to be
related to lower levels of political trust ( Weil, 1989 ). In
addition, extensive research effort has been devoted to the
effects of winning and losing elections on political trust in
different institutional contexts. Anderson and Guillory
(1997) demonstrated that losers were more trusting in
consensual systems than in majoritarian systems and
winners were more trusting in majoritarian than consen-
sual systems. Hence, the gap in political trust is larger in
S. Marien / Electoral Studies 30 (2011) 712
726
715
majoritarian systems than in consensual systems. This
rmed in subsequent research (e.g. Criado
and Herreros, 2007 ). However, these studies make
a distinction between two institutional systems based on
elements such as the state structure, the number of legis-
lative chambers, judicial reviews, parliamentary or presi-
dential system etc. From these studies, it is unclear which
features of these systems are decisive. Later research
concluded that proportional systems affected political trust
levels of winners and losers ( Anderson et al., 2005 ).
However, this conclusion needs to be quali
nding was con
Fig. 1. Visualizing hypothesis 1.
ed, while their
analyses yielded a positive effect of proportional electoral
systems on political trust, the differential effect of these
systems on winners and losers was less convincing. 1 Finally
in the outline of the theoretical arguments, clarity of
responsibility was also stated to have a positive effect on
political trust levels. In empirical research, particular
attention has been paid to the relationship between
economic evaluations and political trust in different insti-
tutional settings ( Powell and Whitten, 1993; Criado and
Herreros, 2007 ). The study of Anderson (2000) esta-
blished for example that the relationship between the
evaluation of economic performance and political trust is
stronger when mechanisms of accountability are simple i.e.
when the institutional context clari
a curvilinear relationship between the proportionality of
election outcomes and political trust. Inclusiveness and
accountability both foster political trust, therefore, political
trust is highest in countries with very proportional as well
as very disproportional election outcomes and it is lowest
in countries that fall in between. This theoretical expecta-
tion can be summarized in the following hypothesis which
is also visualized in Fig. 1 :
H1 . A curvilinear relationship exists between the degree
of proportionality of election outcomes and political trust.
Political trust is highest if either election outcomes are
very proportional or very disproportional. Conversely,
a mixture of both results in lower levels of political trust.
In addition, the effect of a broad range of election
outcomes on political trust will be investigated. Firstly, the
number of choices that are presented to the electorate. The
hypothesis is that the more political parties participate in
elections, the higher the level of political trust in
a country. Also the inclusiveness of the legislature was
argued to increase political trust. Further, we hypothesize
that more political parties in of
es who is in charge of
policymaking (based on Powell and Whitten
s index of
clarity of responsibility), when the target of credit and
blame is large (coalitions), and when citizens have fewer
viable alternative choices (operationalized as parties in
parliament).
In sum, theoretical approaches underlie the argument
that both proportional and disproportional outcomes foster
political trust. Empirical research yielded evidence sup-
porting both claims or
nding no relation between pro-
portionality and political trust ( Lijphart, 1999; Norris, 2011 :
217
ce results in lower levels
of political trust. Another mechanism includes the diffe-
rence in winning and losing elections under different
electoral outcomes. In this study, we will test whether
election losers have higher levels of political trust in
countries with more proportional election outcomes than
in countries with less proportional election outcomes. A
last mechanism relates to the differences in clarity of
responsibility under different electoral outcomes. We
hypothesize that the more diffuse nature of coalition
governments decreases the effect of institutional perfor-
mance on political trust. Below these ve explanations are
summarized:
H2 . Political trust is higher in countries with more poli-
tical parties participating in elections.
H3 . Political trust is higher in countries with more poli-
tical parties in parliament.
235; Listhaug et al., 2009 ). One possible explanation is
the operationalization of proportionality. Often empirical
studies look at the electoral design and divide electoral
systems in three or four categories. This is a rather crude
measure as it looks at the design rather than the effective
electoral outcomes of these systems and ignores the vari-
ance in proportionality within these systems. Some
empirical studies simplify things even more using only two
categories of systems
which are not only based on electoral rules but take also
other system properties such as the state structure or the
executive into account. Although it is useful to take these
features into account, it becomes dif
majoritarian
and
consensual
cult to disentangle
which features affect political trust. Another explanation is
that both arguments are valid and the two competing
hypotheses
can be brought
together by proposing
H4 . Political trust is lower in countries with more parties
in of
ce.
1 While there was an interaction term for
included in the regression explaining political trust, there was no inter-
action between
loser
and
new democracy
H5 . Political trust of election losers is higher in countries
with proportional election outcomes than in countries with
disproportional election outcomes.
H6 . The effect of the evaluation of perceived institutional
performance on political trust is stronger when a single
party is in of
le
was split in four parts according to electoral systems and separate
regressions were run. The different coef
loser
and
disproportionality
included. Instead, the
were not substantially different and missed standard levels of statistical
signi
loser
cients for the variable
cance.
In further analyses comparing
the losers
in different
systems, the variable
disproportionality
was signi
cant in some cases
ce than a coalition government.
but most often not.
887560969.006.png 887560969.007.png
716
S. Marien / Electoral Studies 30 (2011) 712
726
5. Data and methods
Table 1
Political trust.
5.1. Presentation of the data and variables
Political trust
Trust in country
s parliament
0.875
The third and fourth wave of the European Social
Survey (2006
Trust in political parties
0.945
Trust in politicians
0.933
2008) will be used to assess the relationship
between proportionality and political trust. The European
Social Survey (2006, 2008) provides reliable and up-to-
date information on trust in political institutions in 23
European countries with a substantial range of variation in
proportionality. 2 This dataset is ideally suited for
comparative analysis since particular attention has been
paid to ensure comparability with regards to the ope-
rationalization and cross-cultural validity of concepts in
the participating countries. Data were collected between
2006 and 2009 by means of uniform face-to-face inter-
views among representative samples of the population of
23 European countries ( Jowell et al., 2007, 2009 ). 3 Given
the small time-span between both waves and the rather
stable nature of trust in political institutions on the indi-
vidual level (e.g. Hooghe and Wilkenfeld, 2008 ), wave 3
and wave 4 of the European social survey were merged
into one dataset broadening the number of countries, and
in particular the range in the proportionality of election
outcomes included in the analyses. Response rates varied
by country with a mean of 63% ( Jowell et al., 2007, 2009 ).
Given the cross-sectional nature of the data, we cannot
directly test the causality of the relationship between
election outcomes and political trust.
Eigenvalue
2.53
Explained variance (%)
84.30
Extraction method: principal component analysis.
summary of the three items which ranges from 0 to 30
with a mean of 11.33 and a standard deviation of 6.65
(Cronbach
a
s
: 0.90).
5.1.2. Independent variables
In most empirical research, electoral systems are being
categorized into three or four groups namely majoritarian
systems, mixed (independent or dependent) systems and
proportional systems. However, within these systems there
is a substantial variation in the proportionality of the
election outcomes depending on e.g. district size or legal
thresholds. In order to take this variation into account, we
will use Gallagher
s disproportionality index ( 1991;
Gallagher and Mitchell, 2008 ) that looks at the degree to
which the allocation of seats matches the distribution of
the national vote at the parliamentary elections. 5 High
values on this index indicate disproportional election
outcomes. Given that most authors argue that accumulated
experience with the electoral system (and proportional or
disproportional election outcomes)
in
uences political
trust,
s index of disproportionality was
calculated for each country based on the election outcomes
of the past 10 years. 6 The number of alternatives that is
presented to the electorate is measured by looking at the
number of effective parties contesting elections during the
last election before the survey was administered based
upon Laakso and Taagepera (1979) . 7 The inclusiveness of
the Gallagher
5.1.1. Dependent variable
The question on political trust in ESS (2006, 2008) was
phrased:
10 how much you
personally trust each of the institutions I read out.
0 means you do not trust an institution at all, and 10
means you have complete trust.
please tell me on a score of 0
The institutions include:
the national parliament, politicians and political parties. 4
Principal component analysis indicated that the three
items loaded strongly on a single dimension, explaining
84.30% of the total variance with an Eigenvalue of 2.53
( Table 1 ). This is in-line with previous research which has
also found trust in political institutions to be one-
dimensional ( Zmerli et al., 2007; Hooghe, 2011 ). Conse-
quently, an index was created as a simple additive
5 This index is calculated by taking the square root of the sum of the
squared differences of each party
s relative share of the votes and its rela-
tive share of the seats. In theory, this index can range from 0 to 100. A value
of 0 indicates that all political parties receive the same percentage of seats
than of votes. A value of 100 indicates that Party A e.g. gained all the votes
and none of the seats, while Party B did not get any votes but gets all the
seats. Inpractice, distance between the percentage of votes and seats exists,
however, it is dif
cult to justify a large discrepancy as a result high values on
this index are less likely and the range of this index is smaller than 0 to 100.
In effect, the largest value in the sample is 21.95 (France in 2006). In
addition, other indices of (dis)proportionality are also available e.g. Rae
index of disproportionality, Loosemore-Hamby index, Sainte-Lague index,
Rose-index. All these indices look at the difference between the percentage
of votes and the percentage seats partieswin at elections. The
2 More countries were surveyed but not all data is already released.
Moreover, the
eldwork in some countries took place during the elec-
tions or government formation making it dif
cult to calculate winners
and losers. Therefore, some respondents were deleted from the data of
Estonia, Ireland and Sweden. For this reason, the data of the Netherlands
in wave 3 and Ukraine in Wave 4 were also not included.
3 Countries included are: Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Cyprus, Denmark,
Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Hungary, Israel, Ireland, the
Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, the Russian Federation, Slovakia,
Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland and the United Kingdom.
4 Unfortunately, trust in government was not included in the datasets.
But research on political trust shows that trust in political institutions
forms one latent concept. From a theoretical perspective, however, we
can argue that electoral outcomes can have different effects on different
objects of trust. Therefore, all analyses were also performed with as
dependent variable respectively trust in the national parliament, trust in
politicians and trust in political parties. From these additional analyses,
the same conclusions can be drawn.
approach of the Gallagher-index, however, prevents that positive and
negative difference cancel each other out. Moreover, this index is oftenused
in research on institutional design.
6 Indices of disproportionality were obtained from www.tcd.ie/
country included in ESS 2006
least squares
8 an average value of disproportionality
was calculated based on the election outcomes of the past 10 years.
7 In particular, the number of effective parties participating in the last
election before the survey was administered in the country was calcu-
lated for the third wave and the fourth wave. When this was not the same
election, which was often the case, the mean of these two indices was
taken. These indices were retrieved from http://www.tcd.ie/Political_
887560969.008.png 887560969.009.png 887560969.010.png 887560969.011.png 887560969.012.png 887560969.013.png 887560969.014.png
Zgłoś jeśli naruszono regulamin